Money as a Tool for Collective Action


Abstract


Complementary currencies are usually seen as a by-product of collective movements for social change or as an institutional tool for local development: they are an outcome of collective action, not the origin of collective mobilisation. Empirical research on the Sardex complementary currency, though, suggests that money may support the emergence of collective action. Traditional economic theory considers any collective benefits provided by the economic system as the secondary effects of individual entrepreneurs seeking to maximise their profits. Entrepreneurs belonging to the Sardex network, though, do associate the use of the Sardex currency with direct collective benefits. This means they consider their business activities to be a form of collective action for promoting the common good of Sardinia's socio-economic development. Using the Sardex currency sets this collective action in motion: some Sardex members also work to expand the Sardex network without any expectation of economic gain.

DOI Code: 10.1285/i20356609v13i1p438

Keywords: common goods; complementary currency; economic activism; politicisation; utilitarianism; Sardex; money; collective action

References


Amato, M. & Fantacci, L. (2013). Saving the Market from Capitalism. Cambridge: Polity.

Amato, M. & Fantacci, L. (2015). Moneta complementare. Milano: Bruno Mondadori.

Atkinson, A. B., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1969). A new view of technological change. The Economic Journal, 79(315), 573-578.

Baldassarri, D. (2009). Collective action. In P. Bearman & P. Hedström (eds.). The Oxford Handbook of Analytical Sociology. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Baldassarri, D. (2015). Cooperative networks: Altruism, group solidarity, reciprocity, and sanctioning in Uganda producer organizations. American Journal of Sociology, 121(2), 355–395.

Bartram, S. M., & Karolyi, G. A. (2006). The impact of the introduction of the Euro on for-eign exchange rate risk exposures. Journal of Empirical Finance, 13(4-5), 519-549.

Bazzani, G. (2020a). When Money Changes Society. The Case of Sardex Money as Com-munity. Wiesbaden: Springer VS. (in print)

Bazzani, G. (2020b). Digital money for sustainable communities. In A. Maurer (ed.). Hand-book of Economic Sociology of the XXI Century. London: Springer. (in print)

Bearman, P. (1993). Relations into Rhetorics: Local Elite Social Structure in Norfolk, Eng-land, 1540–1640. New Brunswick, N.J.: Rutgers University Press.

Beckert, J. (2016). Imagined futures. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Blanc, J. (2013). Community and complementary currencies, practices and research: state of the art. In Unrisd conference international symposium on potential and limits of social and solidar- ity economy—Special session on alternative finance and comple-mentary currencies, 6th, 7th and 8th of May 2013. Geneva. Presentation. Geneva: In-ternational Labour Organization, 2013. http://www.unrisd.org/sseconf.

Bohle, D. (2009). Race to the bottom? Transnational companies and reinforced competi-tion in the enlarged European Union. In B. van Apeldoorn, J. Drahokoupil & L. Horn (eds). Contradictions and Limits of Neoliberal European Governance (pp. 163-186). London: Palgrave Macmillan.

Bosi, L., & Zamponi, L. (2015). Direct social actions and economic crises: The relationship between forms of action and socio-economic context in Italy. Partecipazione e con-flitto, 8(2), 367-391.

Çalışkan, K., & Callon, M. (2009). Economization, part 1: shifting attention from the economy towards processes of economization. Economy and society, 38(3), 369-398.

Calhoun, C. (2015). Democratizing inequalities: dilemmas of the new public participation. New York, NY: New York University Press.

Charmaz, K. (2006). Constructing grounded theory: A practical guide through qualitative analysis. sage. In M. S. Chwe (2001). Rational Ritual: Culture, Coordination, and Com-mon Knowledge. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Clarke, A. E., Friese, C., & Washburn, R. (2016). Situational analysis in practice: Mapping research with grounded theory. London: Routledge.

Corbin, J. M. & Strauss, A. L. (2008). Basics of qualitative research: Techniques and proce-dures for developing grounded theory, Los Angeles, CA: Sage.

Cour-Thimann, P. (2013). Monetary policy and redistribution: information from central bank balance sheets in the Euro area and the US. Review of Economics, 64(3), 293-324.

Crouch, M., & McKenzie, H. (2006). The logic of small samples in interview-based qualita-tive research. Social science information, 45(4), 483-499.

della Porta, D., & Diani, M. (2006). Social Movements: An Introduction. Malden: Black-well.

Dini, P., van der Graaf, S. & Passani, A. (2015). Socio-economic framework for BOLD stakeholders, OpenLaws.eu Deliverable D2.3.d1, European Commission. Available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/62819/

Dodd, N. (2015). Utopianism and the Future of Money. In P. Aspers & N. Dodd (Eds.) Re-imagining Economic Sociology. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Doria, L., & Fantacci, L. (2018). Evaluating complementary currencies: from the assess-ment of multiple social qualities to the discovery of a unique monetary sociali-ty. Quality and Quantity, 52, 1291–1314.

Durkheim, É. (1982) [1895]. The rules of sociological method. London: Palgrave.

Elster, J. (1983). Explaining Technical Change: A Case Study in the Philosophy of Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Elster, J. (1989). The Cement of Society. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Emerson, M. (1992). One market, one money: an evaluation of the potential benefits and costs of forming an economic and monetary union. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Enderlein, H. (2006). The euro and political union: do economic spillovers from monetary integration affect the legitimacy of EMU?. Journal of European Public Policy, 13(7), 1133-1146.

Feldstein, M. (1997). The political economy of the European Economic and Monetary Un-ion: Political sources of an economic liability. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(4), 23-42.

Forno, F. & P. Graziano (2014), Sustainable community movement organisations, Journal of Consumer Culture 14(2): 139-157.

Goodhart, C. A. (1998). The two concepts of money: implications for the analysis of op-timal currency areas. European Journal of Political Economy, 14(3), 407-432.

Gould, R. (1993). Collective Action and Network Structure. American Sociological Review, 58, 182–96.

Gould, R. (1995). Insurgent Identities: Class, Community, and Protest in Paris from 1948 to the Commune. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

Hardin, R. (1982), Collective Action. Baltimora, MD: Johns Hopkins

University Press.

Hedström, P. (2005). Dissecting the Social: On the Principles of Analytical Sociology. Cam-bridge: Cambridge University Press.

Helleiner, E. (2003). The Making of National Money: Territorial Currencies in Historical Perspective. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

Holland, J. H., Holyoak, K., Nisbett, E., & Thagard, P. (1986). Induction: Processes of In-ference, Learning, and Discovery. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Hopkin, J., & Blyth, M. (2012). What can Okun teach Polanyi? Efficiency, regulation and equality in the OECD. Review of international political economy, 19(1), 1-33.

Kim, H., & Bearman, P. S. (1997). The Structure and Dynamics of Movement Participation. American Sociological Review, 62, 70–93.

Ingham, G (2004). The Nature of Money, Cambridge: Polity.

Littera, G., Sartori, L., Dini, P. & Antoniadis, P. (2014). From an idea to a scalable working model: merging economic benefits with social values in Sardex. In Inaugural WINIR Conference, 11-14 September 2014, Greenwich, London, UK. Available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/59406/

Lubbers, M., & Coenders, M. (2017). Nationalistic attitudes and voting for the radical right in Europe. European Union Politics, 18(1), 98-118.

MacKenzie, D., Muniesa F., & Siu L. (2007). Do Economist make Markets? On the Per-formativity of Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Marres, N. (2016). Material participation: technology, the environment and everyday pub-lics. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

Marx, K. (1963) [1852]. The Eighteenth Brumaire of Louis Bonaparte. New York: Interna-tional.

Marwell, G., & Oliver, P. E. (1993). The Critical Mass in Collective Action: A Microsocial Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Matthijs, M., & Blyth, M. (Eds.). (2015). The future of the Euro. Oxford: Oxford University Press, USA.

McAdam, D. (1999) [1982]. Political Process and the Development of Black Insurgency: 1930–1970. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

McAdam, D., McCarthy, J., & Zald, M. N. (1996). Comparative Perspectives on Social Movements: Political Opportunities, Mobilizing Structures and Cultural Framing. Cam-bridge: Cambridge University Press.

Merton, R. K. (1948). The self-fulfilling prophecy. The Antioch Review, 8(2), 193-210.

Münch, Richard. (2008). Constructing a European Society by Jurisdiction. European Law Journal, 14(5), 519–41.

Olson, M. (1965). The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Ac-tion. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.

Ostrom, E. (2000). Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms. Journal of Eco-nomic Perspectives, 14(3), 137–58.

Papaioannou, E., & Portes, R. (2008). Costs and benefits of running an international cur-rency. Directorate General Economic and Financial Affairs (DG ECFIN), European Commission, no. 348.

Peersman, G., & Smets, F. (2005). The industry effects of monetary policy in the euro ar-ea. The Economic Journal, 115(503), 319-342.

Place, C., & Bindewald, L. (2015). Validating and improving the impact of complementary currency systems through impact assessment frameworks. International Journal of Community Currency Research, 19(D), 152-164.

Rappaport, S. (1996). Abstraction and unrealistic assumptions in economics. Journal of Economic Methodology, 3(2), 215–36.

Rydgren, J. (2009). Beliefs. In P. Hedström & P. S. Bearman (Eds.) (2009). The Oxford handbook of analytical sociology. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Sartori, L., & Dini, P. (2016). From complementary currency to institution: a micro-macro study of the Sardex mutual credit system. Stato e mercato, 36(2), 273-304.

Schmidt-Wellenburg, C. (2017). Europeanisation, stateness, and professions: what role do economic expertise and economic experts play in European political integration? European Journal of Cultural and Political Sociology, 4(4), 430-456.

Servet, J.-M. (2013) Monnaie complémentaire versus microcredit solidaire et tontines: contribution compare à un développement solidaire local. In Unrisd conference inter-national symposium on potential and limits of social and solidarity economy, 6th, 7th and 8th of May 2013. Geneva. Draft paper. Geneva: International Labour

Organiza-tion, 2013. Available on http://www.unrisd.org/sseconf

Simmel, G. (1990) [1907]. The Philosophy of Money. London: Routledge.

Streeck, W. (2015). Why the euro divides Europe. New Left Review, 95, 5-26.

Stroebe, W., & Frey, B. S. (1982). Self‐interest and collective action: The economics and psychology of public goods. British Journal of Social Psychology, 21(2), 121-137.

Tarrow, S. (1998) [1994]. Power in Movement—Social Movements and Contentious Poli-tics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Tilly, C. (1978), From Mobilization to Revolution. Reading, MA: Addison Wesley.

Trenz, H. J., & Triandafyllidou, A. (2017). Complex and dynamic integration processes in Europe: intra EU mobility and international migration in times of recession. Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies, 43(4), 546-559.

Zagzebski, L. T. (2015). Epistemic authority: A theory of trust, authority, and autonomy in belief. Oxford: Oxford University Press.


Full Text: PDF

Refbacks

  • There are currently no refbacks.


Creative Commons License
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribuzione - Non commerciale - Non opere derivate 3.0 Italia License.